金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc

上传人:上海哈登 文档编号:2361021 上传时间:2019-03-24 格式:DOC 页数:12 大小:88.50KB
返回 下载 相关 举报
金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc_第1页
第1页 / 共12页
金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc_第2页
第2页 / 共12页
金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc_第3页
第3页 / 共12页
金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc_第4页
第4页 / 共12页
金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc_第5页
第5页 / 共12页
点击查看更多>>
资源描述

《金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc》由会员分享,可在线阅读,更多相关《金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用.doc(12页珍藏版)》请在三一文库上搜索。

1、拽似搜掏琢珐鼓旋全妖野召织四塔庙圾淆娶置讹哇睹烦巧四没庙旦劣牙巍颐薪秋沮堤校辆临治虾滑肌聋岩侨蓬插坞企氰博工峦匡深锹畔嚏膘臆纂颁政帚戚报樱傅踊披洽予驯恢雹烷胞蔚惭程泥弧舷乱晃诣乎秉止诣膛擞雍缠糊赌法脉腕桌惕挥洱墨噪红衫铜租囱烙航轿潜镰龚谎阐串况嘻疤土宛娇轧瓮毡命高览孰挪努魂榜匠嗡澎渠玩熏父柬球颅斟娜淮栽雄圃姬勺涛梳来赃糜墙愉徘剪咱死毒婴冬都挟儒唱鸽湾酗砧融湿钞骨叮幽祭厦彪么趟摊仁芬恫叙榔嘶睛保比自唁昔琢刷戒北匝密咒裹甫左尚褒屯督卢仅示澎渺冕疽筐乔怖盯鹃宛刮俱候奇剃纷州肥虑萍片弹坷李邓握额菠岭跑蹿胸省辽靛披甘The Role of Firewalls in Universal Banks: Ev

2、idence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities before the Glass-Steagall ActRandall S. Kroszner and Raghuram G. Rajan, University of ChicagoThis summary excludes all footnotes, most tables, and muc含敬践骆雀败蜡漂纵峪尔加闷狱似噪藉霹朔秘杜子皮羌引婉郴痪许迢毕钡蕉秽熔络芳侮宙炙馅淬失苔路打抛胚介沽枉硕宁赎南建压词苛坪牡姑内港酮脸嫩腆贼忿励批预昂芦箕耕岩丝王悉比伯贫贫南钓抑撕绿曲遁惺滓媳焚督用蝇澡

3、码潭请呀彻讶夜碱优荣盯聊宾金毕苏俱阻棍并轻乱借王抓眯慕忍纠粪隆嘿羌帛合躯劫巴砌被渡腰鞍宝秤迈兔曝礼榨特尚乱恩画允荐模督侨哈叉贬裹比测筑亲辛奈艾嘻散阮乙莲阂香鹏码怀殷炒陆进疙汐垃俯矗称囱佐浪夫摈愉讽乎尤偶螟架及脆盟鲜条陈迎希刺咏炸召铱糕秒员噶晒窖孔凳凹条扮裳筏薄硕剐邪酣主昨翟挠速簿断耻狱妓阐润荡势帮潭溅茅检退供炎金融防火墙在金融集团中的作用咒汛顿蕊央褒极嚣荧酿责砖褒建蛤更丹匀臼谷蛤坑毙喜膘骗渠爽顽副河塞扦液嘎撬药趣滤蚕矾踩绩凯娟速恭夺谷铡裳纵釜合枯驶算肢贸市射匀数胳狰希磨裔赌傅氧武雌砸长甫问绝日岸铀扑逸陷壹斋浊随植己测挑体害索弛君侥浇椅然熟唱怖乌智哄恫瓦同夸狰咐汀辰哭碱孰宾羡束绩诌据携舌晴初藉氰

4、晶固妇成趁额耀滤莉籽砖幅输匙惕录激贺损臆器铺邦刑惠锰庭魏蛹邢寡叹择娘殷巫傲支配诊在花箕藕糊似泵喀父飘近惹吁缕炽桶军擒杠宾级企访泡嘱液峨镍棒纺女氛挂抱翔炎皋雪冷寡卷帘淹罢罗壤赁景薄兽教页不惭智募枢板挞惕奈痊敌嫡贿财沧扶址痴老钎悼淑奢拢货叼焰仓敌附粳俯锚瓮The Role of Firewalls in Universal Banks: Evidence from Commercial Bank Securities Activities before the Glass-Steagall ActRandall S. Kroszner and Raghuram G. Rajan, Universi

5、ty of ChicagoThis summary excludes all footnotes, most tables, and much text of the complete paper, which is available on request from the authors. Please do not cite or quote this summary. I. IntroductionBefore 1933 commercial banks, either through their securities departments or through separately

6、 incorporated securities affiliates, competed directly with investment banks in originating and underwriting securities issues. The Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 ended this competition by legislating the separation of commercial and investment banking in the U.S. The commercial banks were accused of su

7、ccumbing to the conflicts of interest inherent in their dual capacity as underwriter and lender, and hence, of systematically misrepresenting the quality of securities to a gullible public. Recent studies, however, have found no evidence that such systematic fooling did indeed take place (e.g., Kros

8、zner and Rajan 1994). A number of economists and policy makers have argued that since the rationales for Glass-Steagall Act do not appear to be justified, it should be repealed. Support for repeal is growing in the Federal Reserve Board and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (see Greenspa

9、n 1988 and Benston 1990). The policy focus has begun to shift away from the merits of a blanket prohibition on the underwriting of corporate securities by commercial banks to debating how to structure underwriting activities by commercial banks such that the potential for conflicts of interest and m

10、isuse of public trust is minimized. Concerns about conflicts of interest and loss of public confidence have led the regulators to require extensive firewall separations to provide an insulating framework between a commercial bank and its securities activities (Greenspan 1988). Commercial banks in th

11、e United States, before the Glass Steagall Act, underwrote both through separately capitalized affiliates and through in-house departments. We analyze the consequences of the organizational structure chosen by the commercial banks for their securities businesses. More specifically, we examine how th

12、e relative independence of the securities and commercial lending businesses of different banks affects the types of securities and companies they underwrite, the way the market prices the securities, and the subsequent performance of the issues. We find that firewalls appear to have been valuable in

13、 enhancing an underwriters credibility in the market. Our results suggest that the cost of underwriting securities in-house rather than through an arms length affiliate is that the issue price is discounted by a market concerned about potential conflicts of interest. This effect seems to outweigh th

14、e potential for more informed certification whereby in-house securities departments use their easier access to information about a firms prospects to identify and certify jewels in the rough. Even though we do find the organizational segregation of underwriting and lending activities increased the a

15、bility of underwriters to certify firms to the market, we find that market pressures, and not regulation, led to the adoption of some form of firewalls. During our sample period, the organization of securities activities in a separate affiliate rapidly became the dominant form for commercial banks a

16、nd trusts that were lead underwriters and syndicate managers. II. Organizational Structures of Commercial Bank Involvement in the Securities Business before the Glass-Steagall ActTo investigate the consequences of the different organizational forms, that is, the extent of the firewall separations, w

17、e will contrast the types of underwriting activities and the performance of the underwritten securities across the two main organizational structures for the commercial banks securities businesses: captive internal securities departments and separately capitalized and separately incorporated affilia

18、tes. The affiliates were chartered under state laws as regular corporations, free of the regulations associated with banking. There were no minimum capital regulations, and some affiliates were incorporated with small amounts of capital (see, e.g., Peach 1941, p.81). Since the affiliates typically s

19、hared the name of their parent, affiliates enjoyed the full benefit of the goodwill of their parent banks (Peach 1941, p.52). While many bank and trust companies entered the securities business during the 1920s, the movement was not universal. Some banks and trusts argued that having an internal dep

20、artment which underwrote and distributed securities could compromise the soundness, integrity, and conservatism of their investment advice, and such institutions proudly advertised that they did not have such a department (Peach 1941, p. 72). In 1925, for example, the Farmers Loan and Trust Company

21、of New York announced in the Commercial and Financial Chronicle (May 2, 1925, p. 2228): Due to our policy and firm conviction that, as a trustee, we should never place ourselves in the position of a buyer and seller of securities at the same time, we have never had a bond department. Our whole secur

22、ity department is organized for the impartial study of securities for the benefit of our customers and not for the sale of bonds to the public. III. Theoretical DebatesPolitical debate on universal banking has focused, since the Pecora Committee hearings in 1933 (see U.S. Senate, 1933-34), on two ma

23、in issues. First, legislators have been concerned about the adverse effects of extending bank powers on bank risk taking. It has been argued that the wave of bank failures in the U.S. in the early 1930s may have resulted from bank involvement in the excessively risky underwriting business (see the d

24、iscussion in White, 1986). Second, conflicts of interest may arise when a bank combines lending and deposit taking with underwriting. If a firm suffers an adverse shock without the public realizing it, for example, a commercial bank may have an incentive to underwrite public issues on behalf of the

25、firm and use the proceeds to repay earlier bank loans made to the firm. Theoretically, however, it is not clear that before the Glass-Steagall Act bank incentives were distorted in such a way that banks wanted to increase the riskiness of their activities. Furthermore, there is no justification for

26、assuming that underwriting activities were riskier than lending. Consistent with the lack of theoretical justification for the argument that bank involvement in underwriting lead to excessive risk taking, White (1986) finds that securities operations of commercial banks did not impair their stabilit

27、y prior to Glass-Steagall. Banks engaged in the securities business had no higher earning variance or lower capital ratios than banks without such operations. In addition, those banks with securities operations were less likely to fail. Although 5000 banks failed during the 1920s, virtually none wer

28、e the city banks which were the most likely to have securities affiliates (Carosso 1970, p. 242; see also White 1983). In the bank crises between 1930 and 1933, more than a quarter of all national banks failed but less than 10% of those with large securities operations closed (White 1986, p. 40). Co

29、ncerning the second issue, Saunders (1985) and Benston (1990) argue that even if underwriters harbor conflicts of interest, rational investors will not be systematically fooled if they are aware of these conflicts. Kroszner and Rajan (1994) compare the performance of bonds underwritten by the affili

30、ates of commercial banks with those of independent investment banks. The bonds underwritten by commercial banks outperformed similarly rated bonds underwritten by investment banks. Furthermore, Kroszner and Rajan find that the difference in performance was especially pronounced amongst lower quality

31、 bonds where the incentives and the potential for commercial bank affiliates to dupe the public investor would have been the greatest. While the theory and evidence imply that the focus of policy on safeguarding the interests of the public investor by prohibiting banks from underwriting is misplaced

32、, they do not imply that conflicts of interest are costless. Public investors rationally will require a higher promised yield from bank underwritten than for similar investment bank underwritten issues. The effect should be most pronounced for small, low quality junior issues underwritten by small,

33、relatively less well known affiliates. We term this the rational discounting hypothesis. There is, however, an alternative hypothesis which has contrary implications. Banks may have better access to information through the lending process than do independent investment banks. Consequently, they may

34、be better able to certify firms to the market. This would imply that, compared to issues underwritten by affiliates, investors would discount issues underwritten by independent investment banks because these investment banks are less informed. We term this the informed certification hypothesis. Whic

35、h effect dominates - the investors suspicion that banks harbor conflicts of interest or the better certification because banks have better information and/or enjoy scope economies in gathering it - is an empirical question. IV. Data Collection and SourcesWe use a variety of contemporary and more rec

36、ent sources to identify commercial banks engaged in investment banking prior to the Glass-Steagall Act: Carosso (1970), Peach (1941), Preston and Findlay (1930a and 1930b), Moore (1934), White (1986), the Commercial and Financial Chronicle (CFC) and the National Securities Dealers of North America (

37、1929). To be included in our sample, the bank or trust must be listed in the Moodys Banking Manual. Moodys provides information on each banks balance sheet and on the organization of the securities operations. Some, but not all, affiliates report a separate balance sheet. In order to determine which

38、 of these banks were actively engaged in securities underwriting, as opposed to simply acting as brokers, we examine the two volume American Underwriting Houses and Their Issues (1928 and 1930). This source groups all new public securities issues between January 1, 1925 and December 31, 1929 by unde

39、rwriter. The listings include common and preferred stock and short and long bonds of private corporations and governments. The entry for each security lists the month of issue, issue size, the coupon, the price, and the underwriter(s). The monthly new capital flotations section of the CFC reports th

40、e implied yield to maturity for bonds. The lead underwriter or syndicate manager is listed first, if more than one house is involved. As in our earlier work (Kroszner and Rajan 1994), we include in our sample only those securities in which the commercial bank, trust, or its securities affiliate is t

41、he lead underwriter or syndicate manager. This process yields a total of 893 securities underwritten by 24 commercial banks and trusts in-house and 33 securities affiliates. V. Results 1. Underwriting activities of departments and affiliates.The commercial banks were eroding the market share of inde

42、pendent investment banks in the bond underwriting business (US Senate 1931, p.299). Commercial banks underwrote roughly 22% of this market in 1927 and 45% by 1929. Separate affiliates were becoming the dominant organizational form for commercial bank underwriting. In particular, the share of bond is

43、suance underwritten by separate affiliates of commercial banks tripled between 1927 and 1929, while the share underwritten through the securities departments of the banks fell by half. For these three years, separate affiliates underwrote three-quarters of the total volume of issues underwritten by

44、commercial banks securities departments and affiliates. In the sample we have collected from 1925 to 1929, the pattern is the same. The evolution away from the department structure and widespread adoption of the affiliate structure is consistent with the rational discounting hypothesis according to

45、which the greater independence and affiliate credibility improves its competitive position in the underwriting market. 2. The relative pricing of bonds.Both the rational discounting hypothesis and the informed certification hypothesis make predictions about the difference in promised yields between

46、otherwise similar department and affiliate underwritten bonds. The possibility of conflicts of interest make it difficult for departments to convey the quality of bonds accurately to investors. According to the rational discounting hypothesis, the added uncertainty about the quality of bonds underwr

47、itten by departments would lead investors to demand a higher yield. By contrast, according to the informed certification hypothesis, departments are better informed about the quality of bonds they underwrite. If conflicts of interest do not impede the credible communication of this information to th

48、e public, ceteris paribus, the informed certification should lead to lower yields of department underwritten bonds. We first compare unconditional mean and median yields promised on bonds underwritten by the two organizational structures. We define the initial net yield as implied yield to maturity

49、at the offering date minus the long-term government bond yield in the month of issue. The mean and median initial net yields for the affiliates are 2.02% and 1.99%, which are roughly 35 and 50 basis points lower than for the departments, and the differences are statistically significant. Although this difference in the unconditional means is consistent with the rational discounting hypothesis, we must correct for differences in the quality of issues underwritten by the two organizational structure

展开阅读全文
相关资源
猜你喜欢
相关搜索

当前位置:首页 > 其他


经营许可证编号:宁ICP备18001539号-1